Logout succeed
Logout succeed. See you again!

Solutions Manual Foundations of Mathematical Economics PDF
Preview Solutions Manual Foundations of Mathematical Economics
Solutions Manual Foundations of Mathematical Economics Michael Carter November 15, 2002 βc 2001 Michael Carter Solutions for Foundations of Mathematical Economics All rights reserved Chapter 1: Sets and Spaces 1.1 {1,3,5,7...} or {πβπ :π is odd} 1.2 Every π₯ β π΄ also belongs to π΅. Every π₯ β π΅ also belongs to π΄. Hence π΄,π΅ have precisely the same elements. 1.3 Examples of ο¬nite sets are β the letters of the alphabet {A, B, C, ... , Z} β the set of consumers in an economy β the set of goods in an economy β the set of players in a game. Examples of inο¬nite sets are β the real numbers β β the natural numbers π β the set of all possible colors β the set of possible prices of copper on the world market β the set of possible temperatures of liquid water. 1.4 π ={1,2,3,4,5,6},πΈ ={2,4,6}. 1.5 The player set is π ={Jenny,Chris}. Their action spaces are π΄ ={Rock,Scissors,Paper} π=Jenny,Chris π 1.6 The setofplayersis π ={1,2,...,π}. The strategyspace ofeachplayeris the set of feasible outputs π΄ ={π ββ :π β€π } π π + π π where π is the output of dam π. π 1.7 The player set is π ={1,2,3}. There are 23 =8 coalitions, namely π«(π)={β ,{1},{2},{3},{1,2},{1,3},{2,3},{1,2,3}} There are 210 coalitions in a ten player game. 1.8 Assume that π₯ β (π βͺπ)π. That is π₯ β/ π βͺπ. This implies π₯ β/ π and π₯ β/ π, or π₯ β ππ and π₯ β ππ. Consequently, π₯ β ππ β©ππ. Conversely, assume π₯ β ππβ©ππ. This implies that π₯ β ππ and π₯ β ππ. Consequently π₯ β/ π and π₯ β/ π and therefore π₯β/ πβͺπ. This implies that π₯β(πβͺπ)π. The other identity is proved similarly. 1.9 βͺ π =π πβπ β© π =β πβπ 1 βc 2001 Michael Carter Solutions for Foundations of Mathematical Economics All rights reserved π₯ 2 1 π₯ 1 -1 0 1 -1 Figure 1.1: The relation {(π₯,π¦):π₯2+π¦2 =1} 1.10 The sample space of a single coin toss is {π»,π}. The set of possible outcomes in three tosses is the product { {π»,π}Γ{π»,π}Γ{π»,π}= (π»,π»,π»),(π»,π»,π),(π»,π,π»), } (π»,π,π),(π,π»,π»),(π,π»,π),(π,π,π»),(π,π,π) A typical outcome is the sequence (π»,π»,π) of two heads followed by a tail. 1.11 π β©βπ ={0} + where0=(0,0,...,0)istheproductionplanusingnoinputsandproducingnooutputs. To see this, ο¬rst note that 0 is a feasible production plan. Therefore, 0 β π. Also, 0ββπ and therefore 0βπ β©βπ. + + Toshowthatthereisnootherfeasibleproductionplaninβπ, weassumethecontrary. + That is, we assume there is some feasible production plan yββπ β{0}. This implies + the existence of a plan producing a positive output with no inputs. This technological infeasible, so that π¦ β/ π. 1.12 1. Let x β π(π¦). This implies that (π¦,βx) βπ. Let xβ² β₯ x. Then (π¦,βxβ²)β€ (π¦,βx) and free disposability implies that (π¦,βxβ²)βπ. Therefore xβ² βπ(π¦). 2. Again assume x β π(π¦). This implies that (π¦,βx) β π. By free disposal, (π¦β²,βx)βπ for every π¦β² β€π¦, which implies that xβπ(π¦β²). π(π¦β²)βπ(π¦). 1.13 The domain of β<β is {1,2}=π and the range is {2,3}β«π. 1.14 Figure 1.1. 1.15 Therelationβisstrictlyhigherthanβistransitive,antisymmetricandasymmetric. It is not complete, reο¬exive or symmetric. 2 βc 2001 Michael Carter Solutions for Foundations of Mathematical Economics All rights reserved 1.16 The following table lists their respective properties. < β€ = β β reο¬exive Γ β β β transitive β β symmetric Γ β asymmetric Γ Γ β β β anti-symmetric β β complete Γ Note that the properties of symmetry and anti-symmetry are not mutually exclusive. 1.17 LetβΌbeanequivalencerelationofasetπ β=β . Thatis,therelationβΌisreο¬exive, symmetricandtransitive. We ο¬rstshowthateveryπ₯βπ belongsto someequivalence class. Let π be any element in π and let βΌ (π) be the class of elements equivalent to π, that is βΌ(π)β‘{π₯βπ :π₯βΌπ} Since βΌ is reο¬exive, πβΌπ and so πββΌ(π). Every πβπ belongs to some equivalence class and therefore βͺ π = βΌ(π) πβπ Next, we show that the equivalence classes are either disjoint or identical, that is βΌ(π)β=βΌ(π) if and only if fβΌ(π)β©βΌ(π)=β . First, assume βΌ(π)β©βΌ(π)=β . Then πββΌ(π) but πβ/ βΌ(π). Therefore βΌ(π)β=βΌ(π). Conversely, assume βΌ(π)β©βΌ(π) β= β and let π₯ β βΌ(π)β©βΌ(π). Then π₯ βΌ π and by symmetry π βΌ π₯. Also π₯ βΌ π and so by transitivity π βΌ π. Let π¦ be any element in βΌ(π) so that π¦ βΌ π. Again by transitivity π¦ βΌ π and therefore π¦ β βΌ(π). Hence βΌ(π)ββΌ(π). Similar reasoning implies that βΌ(π)ββΌ(π). Therefore βΌ(π)=βΌ(π). We conclude that the equivalence classes partition π. 1.18 Thesetofpropercoalitionsisnotapartitionofthesetofplayers,sinceanyplayer can belong to more than one coalition. For example, player1 belongs to the coalitions {1}, {1,2} and so on. 1.19 π₯β»π¦ =β π₯βΏπ¦ and π¦ ββΏπ₯ π¦ βΌπ§ =β π¦ βΏπ§ and π§ βΏπ¦ Transitivity of βΏ implies π₯βΏπ§. We need to show that π§ ββΏπ₯. Assume otherwise, that is assume π§ βΏ π₯ This implies π§ βΌ π₯ and by transitivity π¦ βΌ π₯. But this implies that π¦ βΏπ₯ whichcontradicts the assumption that π₯β»π¦. Thereforewe conclude that π§ ββΏπ₯ and therefore π₯β»π§. The other result is proved in similar fashion. 1.20 asymmetric Assume π₯β»π¦. π₯β»π¦ =β π¦ ββΏπ₯ while π¦ β»π₯ =β π¦ βΏπ₯ Therefore π₯β»π¦ =β π¦ ββ»π₯ 3 βc 2001 Michael Carter Solutions for Foundations of Mathematical Economics All rights reserved transitive Assume π₯β»π¦ and π¦ β»π§. π₯β»π¦ =β π₯βΏπ¦ and π¦ ββΏπ₯ π¦ β»π§ =β π¦ βΏπ§ and π§ ββΏπ¦ Since βΏ is transitive, we conclude that π₯βΏπ§. It remains to show that π§ ββΏ π₯. Assume otherwise, that is assume π§ βΏ π₯. We know that π₯βΏπ¦ and transitivity implies that π§ βΏπ¦, contrary to the assumption that π¦ β»π§. We conclude that π§ ββΏπ₯ and π₯βΏπ§ and π§ ββΏπ₯ =β π₯β»π§ This shows that β» is transitive. 1.21 reο¬exive Since βΏ is reο¬exive, π₯βΏπ₯ which implies π₯βΌπ₯. transitive Assume π₯βΌπ¦ and π¦ βΌπ§. Now π₯βΌπ¦ ββ π₯βΏπ¦ and π¦ βΏπ₯ π¦ βΌπ§ ββ π¦ βΏπ§ and π§ βΏπ¦ Transitivity of βΏ implies π₯βΏπ¦ and π¦ βΏπ§ =β π₯βΏπ§ π§ βΏπ¦ and π¦ βΏπ₯ =β π§ βΏπ₯ Combining π₯βΏπ§ and π§ βΏπ₯ =β π₯βΌπ§ symmetric π₯βΌπ¦ ββ π₯βΏπ¦ and π¦ βΏπ₯ ββ π¦ βΏπ₯ and π₯βΏπ¦ ββ π¦ βΌπ₯ 1.22 reο¬exive Every integer is a multiple of itself, that is π=1π. transitive Assume π=ππ and π=ππ where π,π βπ. Then π=πππ so that π is a multiple of π. not symmetric If π = ππ, π β π, then π = 1π and π β/ π. For example, 4 is a π multiple of 2 but 2 is not a multiple of 4. 1.23 [π,π]={π,π¦,π,π§} (π,π)={π¦} 1.24 βΏ(π¦)={π,π¦,π§} β»(π¦)={π,π§} βΎ(π¦)={π,π₯,π¦} βΊ(π¦)={π,π₯} 4 βc 2001 Michael Carter Solutions for Foundations of Mathematical Economics All rights reserved 1.25 Let π be ordered by βΏ. π₯ β π is a minimal element there is no element which strictly precedes it, that is there is no element π¦ β π such that π¦ βΊ π₯. π₯ β π is the ο¬rst element if it precedes every other element, that is π₯βΎπ¦ for all π¦ βπ. 1.26 The maximal elements of π are π and π§. The minimal element of π is π₯. These are also best and worst elements respectively. 1.27 Assume that π₯ is a best element in π orderedby βΏ. That is, π₯βΏπ¦ for all π¦ βπ. Thisimpliesthatthereisnoπ¦ βπ whichstrictlydominatesπ₯. Therefore,π₯ismaximal in π. In Example 1.23, the numbers 5,6,7,8,9 are all maximal elements, but none of them is a best element. 1.28 Assumethattheelementsaredenotedπ₯ ,π₯ ,...,π₯ . Wecanidentifythemaximal 1 2 π element by constructing another list using the following recursive algorithm π =π₯ 1 1 { π₯ if π₯ β»π π = π π πβ1 π π otherwise πβ1 By construction, there is no π₯ which strictly succedes π . π is a maximal element. π π π 1.29 π₯β is maximal ββ there does not exist π₯β»π₯β that is β»(π₯β)={π₯:π₯β»π₯β}=β π₯β is best ββ π₯β βΏπ₯ for every π₯βπ ββ π₯βΎπ₯β for every π₯βπ That is, every π₯βπ belongs to βΎ(π₯β) or βΎ(π₯β)=π. 1.30 Let π΄ be a nonempty set of a set π ordered by βΏ. π₯ β π is a lower bound for π΄ if it precedes every element in π΄, that is π₯ βΎ π for all π β π΄. It is a greatest lower bound if it dominates every lower bound, that is π₯βΏπ¦ for every lower bound π¦ of π΄. 1.31 Any multiple of 60 is an upper bound for π΄. Thus, the set of upper bounds of π΄ is {60,120,240,...}. The least upper bound of π΄ is 60. The only lower bound is 1, hence it is the greatest lower bound. 1.32 The least upper bounds of interval [π,π] are π and π§. The least upper bound of (π,π) is π¦. 1.33 π₯ is an upper bound of π΄ ββ π₯βΏπ for every πβπ΄ ββ πβΎπ₯ for every πβπ΄ ββ π΄ββΎ(π₯) Similarly π₯ is a lower bound of π΄ ββ π₯βΎπ for every πβπ΄ ββ πβΏπ₯ for every πβπ΄ ββ π΄ββΏ(π₯) 5 βc 2001 Michael Carter Solutions for Foundations of Mathematical Economics All rights reserved 1.34 For every π₯ββ2, π₯β»π¦ if π₯ >π¦ or π₯ =π¦ and π₯ >π¦ 1 1 1 1 2 2 Since all elements π₯ββ2 are comparable, β» is complete; it is a total order. 1.35 Assume βΏ is complete for every π. Then for every π₯,π¦ β π and for all π = π 1,2,...,π, either π₯ βΏ π¦ or π¦ βΏ π₯ or both. Either π π π π π π π₯ βΌ π¦ for all π Then deο¬ne π₯βΌπ¦. π π π π₯ ββΌ π¦ for some π Let π be the ο¬rst individual with a strict preference, that is π = π π π min (π₯ ββΌπ¦ ). (Completeness of βΏ ensures that π is deο¬ned). Then deο¬ne π π π π π₯β»π¦ if π₯ β» π¦ π π π π¦ β»π₯ otherwise 1.36 Let π, π and π be subsets of a ο¬nite set π. Set inclusion β is reο¬exive since π βπ. transitive since π βπ and π βπ implies π βπ. anti-symmetric since π βπ and π βπ implies π =π Therefore β is a partial order. 1.37 Assume π₯ and π¦ are both least upper bounds of π΄. That is π₯ βΏ π for all π β π΄ and π¦ βΏ π for all π β π΄. Further, if π₯ is a least upper bound, π¦ βΏ π₯. If π¦ is a least upper bound, π₯βΏπ¦. By anti-symmetry, π₯=π¦. 1.38 π₯βΌπ¦ =β π₯βΏπ¦ and π¦ βΏπ₯ which implies that π₯=π¦ by antisymmetry. Each equivalence class βΌ(π₯)={π¦ βπ :π¦ βΌπ₯} comprises just a single element π₯. 1.39 maxπ«(π)=π and minπ«(π)=β . 1.40 The subset {2,4,8} forms a chain. More generally, the set of integer powers of a given number {π,π2,π3,...} forms a chain. 1.41 Assume π₯ and π¦ are maximal elements of the chain π΄. Then π₯ βΏ π for all π β π΄ and in particular π₯ βΏ π¦. Similarly, π¦ βΏ π for all π β π΄ and in particular π¦ βΏ π₯. Since βΏ is anti-symmetric, π₯=π¦. 1.42 1. By assumption, foreveryπ‘βπβπ,βΊ(π‘)is anonempty ο¬nite chain. Hence, it has a unique maximal element, π(π‘). 2. Let π‘ be any node. Either π‘ is an initial node or π‘ has a unique predecessor π(π‘). Either π(π‘) is an initial node, or it has a unique predecessor π(π(π‘)). Continuing in this way, we trace out a unique path from π‘ back to an initial node. We can be sure of eventually reaching an initial node since π is ο¬nite. 1.43 (1,2)β¨(3,1)=(3,2) and (1,2)β§(3,2)=(1,2) 6 βc 2001 Michael Carter Solutions for Foundations of Mathematical Economics All rights reserved 1.44 1. π₯β¨π¦ isanupperboundfor{π₯,π¦},thatisxβ¨y βΏπ₯andxβ¨yβΏπ¦. Similarly, π₯β¨π¦ is a lower bound for {π₯,π¦}. 2. Assume π₯ βΏ π¦. Then π₯ is an upper bound for {π₯,π¦}, that is π₯ βΏ π₯β¨π¦. If π is any upper bound for {π₯,π¦}, then π βΏ π₯. Therefore, π₯ is the least upper bound for {π₯,π¦}. Similarly, π¦ is a lower bound for {π₯,π¦}, and is greater than any other lower bound. Conversely,assume π₯β¨π¦ =π₯. Then π₯ is an upper bound for {π₯,π¦}, that is π₯βΏπ¦. 3. Using the preceding equivalence π₯βΏπ₯β§π¦ =β π₯β¨(π₯β§π¦)=π₯ π₯β¨π¦ βΏπ₯ =β (π₯β¨π¦)β§π₯=π₯ 1.45 A chain π is a complete partially ordered set. For every π₯,π¦ β π with π₯ β= π¦, either π₯β»π¦ or π¦ β»π₯. Therefore, deο¬ne the meet and join by { π¦ if π₯β»π¦ π₯β§π¦ = π₯ if π¦ β»π₯ { π₯ if π₯β»π¦ π₯β¨π¦ = π¦ if π¦ β»π₯ π is a lattice with these operations. 1.46 Assumeπ andπ arelattices, andletπ =π Γπ . Consideranytwoelements 1 2 1 2 x = (π₯ ,π₯ ) and y = (π¦ ,π¦ ) in π. Since π and π are lattices, π = π₯ β¨π¦ β π 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 and π = π₯ β¨π¦ β π , so that b = (π ,π ) = (π₯ β¨π¦ ,π₯ β¨π¦ ) β π. Furthermore 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 b βΏ x and b βΏ y in the natural product order, so that b is an upper bound for the {x,y}. Every upper bound bΛ = (Λπ ,Λπ ) of {x,y} must have π βΏ π₯ and π βΏ π¦ , 1 2 π π π π π π so that bΛ βΏ b. Therefore, b is the least upper bound of {x,y}, that is b = xβ¨y. Similarly, xβ§y=(π₯ β§π¦ ,π₯ β§π¦ ). 1 1 2 2 1.47 Let π be a subset of π and let πβ ={π₯βπ :π₯βΏπ for every π βπ} be the set of upper bounds ofπ. Then π₯β βπβ β=β . By assumption, πβ has a greatest lower bound π. Since every π β π is a lower bound of πβ, π βΏ π for every π β π. Therefore π is an upper bound of π. Furthermore, π is the least upper bound of π, since πβΎπ₯ for every π₯βπβ. This establishes that every subset of π also has a least upper bound. In particular, every pair of elements has a least upper and a greatest lower bound. Consequently π is a complete lattice. 1.48 Without loss of generality, we will prove the closed interval case. Let [π,π] be an interval in a lattice πΏ. Recall that π = inf[π,π] and π = sup[π,π]. Choose any π₯,π¦ in [π,π]βπΏ. Since πΏ is a lattice, π₯β¨π¦ βπΏ and π₯β¨π¦ =sup{π₯,π¦}βΎπ Therefore π₯β¨π¦ β [π,π]. Similarly, π₯β§π¦ β [π,π]. [π,π] is a lattice. Similarly, for any subsetπ β[π,π]βπΏ,supπ βπΏifπΏiscomplete. Also,supπ βΎπ=sup[π,π]. Therefore supπ β[π,π]. Similarly infπ β[π,π] so that [π,π] is complete. 7 βc 2001 Michael Carter Solutions for Foundations of Mathematical Economics All rights reserved 1.49 1. The strong set order βΏ is π antisymmetric Let π ,π β π with π βΏ π and π βΏ π . Choose π₯ β π 1 2 1 π 2 2 π 1 1 1 and π₯ βπ . Since π βΏ π , π₯ β¨π₯ βπ and π₯ β§π₯ βπ . On the other 2 2 1 π 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 hand, since π βΏπ , π₯ =(π₯ β¨(π₯ β§π₯ )βπ andπ₯ =π₯ β§(π₯ β¨π₯ )βπ 2 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 (Exercise 1.44. Therefore π =π and βΏ is antisymmetric. 1 2 π transitive Let π ,π ,π β π with π βΏ π and π βΏ π . Choose π₯ β π , 1 2 3 1 π 2 2 π 3 1 1 π₯ β π and π₯ β π . Since π βΏ π and π βΏ π , π₯ β¨π₯ and π₯ β§π₯ 2 2 3 3 1 π 2 2 π 3 1 2 2 3 are in π . Therefore π¦ =π₯ β¨(π₯ β§π₯ )βπ which implies 2 2 1 2 3 2 ( ) π₯ β¨π₯ =π₯ β¨ (π₯ β§π₯ )β¨π₯ 1 3 1 2 3 3 ( ) = π₯ β¨(π₯ β§π₯ ) β¨π₯ 1 2 3 3 =π¦ β¨π₯ βπ 2 3 3 since π βΏ π . Similarly π§ =(π₯ β¨π₯ )β§π₯ βπ and 2 π 3 2 1 2 3 2 ( ) π₯ β§π₯ = π₯ β§(π₯ β¨π₯ ) β§π₯ 1 3 1 1 2 3 ( ) =π₯ β§ (π₯ β¨π₯ )β§π₯ 1 1 2 3 =π₯ β§π§ βπ 1 2 1 Therefore, π βΏ π . 1 π 3 2. π βΏ π if and only if, for every π₯ ,π₯ β π, π₯ β¨π₯ β π and π₯ β§π₯ β π, which π 1 2 1 2 1 2 is the case if and only if π is a sublattice. 3. Let πΏ(π) denote the set of all sublattices of π. We have shown that βΏ is π reο¬exive, transitive and antisymmetric on πΏ(π). Hence, it is a partial order on πΏ(π). 1.50 Assume π βΏ π . For any π₯ βπ and π₯ β π , π₯ β¨π₯ β π and π₯ β§π₯ β π . 1 π 2 1 1 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 Therefore supπ βΏπ₯ β¨π₯ βΏπ₯ for every π₯ βπ 1 1 2 2 2 2 which implies that supπ βΏsupπ . Similarly 1 2 infπ βΎπ₯ β§π₯ βΎπ₯ for every π₯ βπ 2 1 2 1 1 1 which implies that infπ βΎ infπ . Note that completeness ensures the existence of 2 1 supπ and infπ respectively. 1.51 An argument analogous to the preceding exercise establishes =β . (Complete- ness is not required, since for any interval π=inf[π,π] and π=sup[π,π]). To establish the converse, assume that π = [π ,π ] and π = [π ,π ]. Consider any 1 1 1 2 2 2 π₯ βπ and π₯ βπ . There are two cases. 1 1 2 2 Case 1. π₯ βΏπ₯ Since π is a chain, π₯ β¨π₯ =π₯ βπ . π₯ β§π₯ =π₯ βπ . 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 Case 2. π₯ βΊπ₯ Since π is a chain, π₯ β¨π₯ = π₯ . Now π βΎ π₯ βΊ π₯ βΎ π βΎ π . 1 2 1 2 2 1 1 2 2 2 Therefore, π₯ = π₯ β¨π₯ β π . Similarly π βΎ π βΎ π₯ βΊ π₯ βΎ π . Therefore 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 2 2 π₯ β§π₯ =π₯ βπ . 1 2 1 2 We have shown that π βΏ π in both cases. 1 π 2 1.52 Assume that βΏ is a complete relation on π. This means that for every π₯,π¦ βπ, either π₯βΏπ¦ or π¦ βΏπ₯. In particular, letting π₯=π¦, π₯βΏπ₯ for π₯βπ. βΏ is reο¬exive. 8 βc 2001 Michael Carter Solutions for Foundations of Mathematical Economics All rights reserved 1.53 Anti-symmetryimpliesthateachindiο¬erenceclasscontainsasingleelement. Ifthe consumerβspreferencerelationwasanti-symmetric,therewouldbe nobasketsofgoods between which the consumer was indiο¬erent. Each indiο¬erence curve which consist a single point. 1.54 We previously showed (Exercise 1.27) that every best element is maximal. To provethe converse,assumethatπ₯ismaximalinthe weaklyorderedsetπ. Wehaveto show that π₯βΏπ¦ for all π¦ βπ. Assume otherwise, that is assume there is some π¦ βπ for which π₯ ββΏ π¦. Since βΏ is complete, this implies that π¦ β» π₯ which contradicts the assumption that π₯ is maximal. Hence we conclude that π₯ βΏ π¦ for π¦ β π and π₯ is a best element. 1.55 False. Achainhasatmostonemaximalelement(Exercise1.41). Here,uniqueness is ensured by anti-symmetry. A weakly ordered set in which the order is not anti- symmetric may have multiple maximal and best elements. For example, π and π are both best elements in the weakly ordered set {πβΌπβ»π}. 1.56 1. For every π₯βπ, either π₯βΏ π¦ =β π₯ββΏ(π¦) or π¦ βΏπ₯ =β π₯ββΎ(π¦) since βΏ is complete. Consequently, βΏ(π¦)βͺβΊ(π¦) = π If π₯ β βΏ(π¦)β©βΎ(π¦), then π₯ βΏ π¦ and π¦ βΏπ₯ so that π₯βΌπ¦ and π₯βπΌ . π¦ 2. For every π₯βπ, either π₯βΏπ¦ =β π₯ββΏ(π¦) or π¦ β»π₯ =β π₯ββΊ(π¦) since βΏ is complete. Consequently, βΏ(π¦)βͺβΊ(π¦)=π and βΏ(π¦)β©βΊ(π¦)=β . 3. For every π¦ β π, β»(π¦) and πΌ partition βΏ(π¦) and therefore β»(π¦), πΌ and βΊ(π¦) π¦ π¦ partition π. 1.57 Assume π₯βΏπ¦ andπ§ ββΏ(π₯). Then π§ βΏπ₯βΏπ¦ by transitivity. Thereforeπ§ ββΏ(π¦). This shows that βΏ(π₯)ββΏ(π¦). Similarly, assume π₯ β» π¦ and π§ β β»(π₯). Then π§ β» π₯ β» π¦ by transitivity. Therefore π§ β β»(π¦). This shows that βΏ(π₯) β βΏ(π¦). To show that βΏ(π₯) β= βΏ(π¦), observe that π₯ββ»(π¦) but that π₯β/ β»(π₯) 1.58 Every ο¬nite ordered set has a least one maximal element (Exercise 1.28). 1.59 Kreps(1990,p.323),Luenberger(1995,p.170)andMas-Colelletal. (1995,p.313) adopt the weak Pareto order, whereas Varian (1992, p.323) distinguishes the two or- ders. Osborneand Rubinstein (1994,p.7) also distinguish the two orders, utilizing the weak order in deο¬ning the core (Chapter 13) but the strong Pareto order in the Nash bargaining solution (Chapter 15). 1.60 Assumethatagroupπ isdecisiveoverπ₯,π¦ βπ. Letπ,πβπ betwootherstates. We have to show that π is decisive over π and π. Without loss of generality, assume for all individuals π βΏ π₯ and π¦ βΏ π. Then, the Pareto order implies that π β» π₯ and π π π¦ β»π. Assume that for every π β π, π₯ βΏ π¦. Since π is decisive over π₯ and π¦, the social π order ranks π₯βΏπ¦. By transitivity, πβΏπ. By IIA, this holds irrespective of individual preferences on other alternatives. Hence, π is decisive over π and π. 1.61 Assume that π is decisive. Let π₯, π¦ and π§ be any three alternatives and assume π₯βΏπ¦ for every πβπ. Partition π into two subgroups π and π so that 1 2 π₯βΏ π§ for every πβπ and π§ βΏ π¦ for every πβπ π 1 π 2 Since π is decisive, π₯βΏπ¦. By completeness, either π₯βΏπ§inwhichcaseπ isdecisiveoverπ₯andπ§. Bytheο¬eldexpansionlemma(Exercise 1 1.60), π is decisive. 1 9